Manifold becomes a battleground for a long-standing debate
It’s not that often that an entirely new system of government is proposed, which is why Robin Hanson’s proposal from the turn of the century for a form of government based around the capability of markets to aggregate information has had some staying power in forecasting circles.
Futarchy, as it’s called, proposes:
Now, I’m sure you’re already thinking of about a thousand reasons why this would fail, but Hanson and other proponents of futarchy have defended it against rote concerns like discount rates making long-term forecasts difficult, perverse incentives such as people betting for the policies they like, market manipulation, etc.
And of course, imagine hearing a basic description of another form of government, like the mixed republic. “So… uh… there are two legislative bodies, in one of which the seats are allocated by population, and in the other the seats are allocated two per state, some of these states are fifty times larger than others… and there’s also a unitary executive who has basically no bounds on their power unless they’re impeached by the legislature… and there’s a constitution which is interpreted by a series of judges appointed by the executive…”
As with everything, the devil is in the details and there’s no such thing as free governance. So much of what makes a system of government viable and robust is the body of political theory and jurisprudence underlying it.
Now, futarchy is not going to supplant the republic any time soon, but it might be useful in limited cases. One classic example from Hanson is that it could be used to make decisions on the investiture of CEOs. You could make markets on whether the stock price of a company would go up if the CEO is fired, and given US law on the responsibility of corporate governance, this actually lines up pretty well with their explicit incentives.
But back in June, blogger Dynomight dropped a fairly aggressive critique of futarchy. They had been writing on the topic for a while, echoing previous sentiments on why futarchy might have trouble disentangling causal relationships from probabilistic relationships, but this new post was fairly clear and if true, they argued, constituted a “fundamental flaw”. That’s worse than a normal flaw.
Here’s the thought experiment that illustrates this. You might want to read this carefully:
It sounds esoteric, but replace coin with policy and flip with “observe outcomes” and you basically have the precise, recommended use-case for futarchy.
In any case… someone made the market.
Manifold user Bolton Bailey did precisely this, and as you can see, market behavior fairly rapidly sent Coin B up to 90%, perhaps even more of a clear demonstration than Dynomight would have expected!
Another user thought that creating derivatives markets for both coins might fix this. It didn’t. Despite the creation of the derivative markets, the main market kept the large discrepancy between the odds for the two coins.
Dynomight then declared victory:
The fact that this is possible is concerning. If this can happen, then futarchy does not work in general. If you want to claim that futarchy works, then you need to spell out exactly what extra assumptions you’re adding to guarantee that this kind of thing won’t happen.
I think it’s a cool market, and it was very astute of Dynomight to predict the market’s dynamics in advance, not something to take for granted.
However, many Manifold users disagreed with this characterization. I thought about the market… then spoke with Isaac King, Manifold’s second-most-prolific market creator, to get his perspective… then I thought about it some more.
Ultimately, I think Dynomight is right in that the edge case they’ve set up is fundamentally flawed and does not do a good job of executing a conditional market with meaningful probabilities. But then I thought about how a similar critique about any other system of government (or really, any tool for governance) might go.
The Republic’s Fundamental Flaw:
Suppose there’s an election to pick which of two parties should run the country. 60% of the population wants Party A to win, and 40% of the population wants Party B to win. I divide everyone in the population up into 10 regions, such that in 6 of the regions, 55% of the population votes for Party B, electing a representative from that party, and in the other 4 regions, 82.5% of the population votes for Party A, electing a representative from that party.
Now, we have 6 representatives from Party B and 4 from Party A, despite a clear majority preferring Party A.
Okay, gerrymandering is of course a real concern with republics, but I don’t think it makes sense to describe it as a fundamental flaw of the system. Perhaps care must be taken to minimize its effects, but it’s one of many, many downsides of that magnitude for a republic.
Thus, I think Dynomight could always retreat to the motte of “care must be taken to avoid designing conditional markets susceptible to this issue,” but I think the bailey is indefensible.
Here are other issues with futarchic systems that one would need to take care to avoid:
In particular, Dynomight and Bolton Bailey’s experimental market has a couple of characteristics where I think the analogy to gerrymandering makes sense. Just like with gerrymandering, it requires some artificial manipulation of the system to get to these unfair outcomes. In particular, it requires:
You can imagine that this thought experiment, which works well for coin flip predictions, might not work so well when the outcome is some complex formula of general welfare outcomes, or something as inscrutable as “stock prices.”
I would say, then, that it makes more sense to describe the “fundamental flaw” of futarchy as being the same as any other system of government. That is that there is no such thing as free lunch in governance. If you attempt to reduce any system of government to some minimalist form where it can be subject to simple and pure experimentation, you’ve essentially broken it irredeemably and it should come as no surprise that it fails to operate as intended.
In any case, another experiment was conducted on Manifold to test futarchy shortly after.
And in this one… futarchy won.
Here were the rules for this experiment:
- Tumbles is allowed to bet on these options when each round starts, but is prohibited from betting on this market within 12 hours of the round ending
- Round ends and decisions are finalized at 4:20 pm PST
- If Tumbles is very late to create a market, resolution will be delayed 24 hours to make sure decision markets are always open for at least 16 hours
- Tumbles locks in his move each round before creating the decision markets for that round
- Decisions are messaged to @Stralor via discord, an ex-user of Manifold with a good reputation, so that moves can be verified if needed
- Decisions are also posted in the comments as an MD5 hash
- Each round there are three options, one for each of Rock/Paper/Scissors
- At resolution time each round (4:20pm), the option with the highest percentage becomes Manifold’s chosen action
- The two options that are not chosen immediately resolve N/A
- This chosen option will stay open until the entire set of RPS games is complete, and resolve based on whether Manifold won the best of seven
- Chosen option is determined based on what can be determined by looking at the regular interface, not the api
- In the case of a tie between two options, RPS rules determine which option is chosen (ROCK beats PAPER, etc)
- In the case of a tie between all three options, ROCK becomes the chosen option
Despite the adversarial format, and despite the fact that there was asymmetric information benefiting Tumbles, futarchy still won, in a closely fought match, 4-3.
Do I actually think this is a meaningful test of the efficacy of futarchy? On one hand… no. On the other hand, the last time that the world got together to beat a master of strategy games, the great Garry Kasparov, they used a mixed democracy, rather than a futarchy, and lost.
Final position from Kasparov vs the world, probably the greatest game of chess ever played.
Futarchy 1, democracy 0.
cross-posted from the Manifold Market newsletter's substack
P.S. This quote from Kasparov that I found on r/singularity amused me (his takes on AI are only a little better now, 36 years later):