Edited!
This is a consequence of decreasing returns to scale! Without decreasing returns to scale, humans could buy some small territory before their labor is obsolete, and they could run a non-automated economy just on that small territory, and the fact that the territory is small would be no problem, since there are no decreasing returns to scale.
Wow, I didn’t read. Their argument does make sense. And it’s intuitive. Arguably this is sort of happening with AI datacenter investment, where companies like Microsoft are reallocating their limited cash flow away from employees (i.e., laying people off) so they can afford to build AI data centers.
A funny thing about their example is that labor would be far better off if they “walled themselves off” in autarky. In their example, wages fall to zero because of capital flight — because there is an “AK sector” that can absorb an infinite amount of capital at high returns, it is impossible to invest in labor-complementary capital unless wages are zero. So my intuition that humans could “always just leave the automated society” still applies, their example just rules it out by assumption.
Here’s a random list of economic concepts that I wish tech people were more familiar with of. I’ll focus on concepts, not findings, and on intuition rather than exposition.
Is it valuable for tech & AI people to try to learn economics? I very much enjoy doing so, but it certainly hasn’t led to direct benefits or directly relevant contributions. So what is the point? (I think there is a point.)
It’s good to know enough to not be tempted to jump to conclusions about AI impact. I’m a big fan of the kind of arguments that the Epoch & Mechanize founders post on Twitter. A quick “wait, really?” check can dispel assumptions that AI must immediately have a huge impact, or conversely that AI can’t have an unprecedentedly fast impact. This is good for sounding smart. But not directly useful (unless I’m talking to someone who is confused).
I also feel like economic knowledge helps give meaning to the things I personally work on. The most basic version of this is when I familiarize myself with quantitative metrics of impact of past technologies (“comparables”), and try to keep up with how the stuff I work on tracks. I think it’s the same joy that some people get by watching sports and trying to quantify how players and teams are performing.
In that world, I think people wouldn’t say “we have AGI”, right? Since it would be obvious to them that most of what humans do (what they do at that time, which is what they know about) is not yet doable by AI.
Your preferred definition would leave the term AGI open to a scenario where 50% of current tasks get automated gradually using technology similar to current technology (i.e., normal economic growth). It wouldn’t feel like “AGI arrived”, it would feel like “people gradually built more and more software over 50 years that could do more and more stuff”.
I’m worried that the recent AI exposure versus jobs papers (1
, 2
) are still quite a distance from an ideal identification strategy of finding “profession twins” that differ only in their exposure to AI. Occupations that are differently exposed to AI are different in countless other ways that are correlated with the impact of other recent macroeconomic shocks.
I was reminded of OpenAI’s definition of AGI, a technology that can “outperform humans at most economically valuable work”, and it triggered a pet peeve of mine: It’s tricky to define what it means for something to make up some percentage of “all work”, and OpenAI was painfully vague about what they meant.
More than 50% of people in England used to work in agriculture, and now it’s far less. But if you said that farming machines “can outperform humans at most economically valuable work” it just wouldn’t make sense. Farming machines obviously don’t perform 50% of current economic value.
The most natural definition, in my opinion, is that even after the economy adjusts, AI would still be able to perform >50% of the economically valuable work. Labor income would make up <<50% of GDP, and AI income would make up >50% of GDP. In a simple Acemoglu/Autor task continuum model of the economy where there is a continuum of tasks, this corresponds to AI doing more than 50% of the tasks.
I don’t think OpenAI’s definition is wrong, exactly, since it does have a reasonably natural interpretation. But I really wish they’d been more clear.
I’ve been trying to better understand the assumptions behind people’s differing predictions of economic growth from AI, and what we can monitor — investment? employment? interest rates? — to narrow down what is actually happening.
I’m not an economist; I am an engineer who implements AI systems. The reason I want to understand the potential impact of AI is because it’s going to matter for my own career and for everyone I know.
In the spirit of “learning in public”, I’ll share what I’ve learned (which is a little) and what’s not making sense to me (which is a lot).
In Ege Erdil’s recent case for multi-decade AI timelines, he gives the following intuition for why a “software-only singularity” is unlikely:
The case for AI revenue growth not slowing down at all, or perhaps even accelerating, rests on the feedback loops that would be enabled by human-level or superhuman AI systems: short timelines advocates usually emphasize software R&D feedbacks more, while I think the relevant feedback loops are more based on broad automation and reinvestment of output into capital accumulation, chip production, productivity improvements, et cetera.
The implicit assumption is that chip production, energy buildouts, and general physical capital accumulation can only go so fast.
Certainly, today’s physical capital stock took a long time to accumulate. With today’s technology, it’s not feasible to scale physical capital formation by 10x, or to 10x the capital stock in 10 years; it would simply be far too expensive.
But economics does not place any theoretical limit on the productivity of new vintages of capital goods. If tomorrow’s technology was far more effective at producing capital goods, physical capital could grow at an unprecedented rate.
(In frontier economies today, the speed of physical capital growth is well below historical records. For reference, South Korea’s physical capital stock grew at ~13.2% per year at the peak of its growth miracle. And from 2004 to 2007, China’s electricity production grew at an average of ~14.2% per year.)
Today’s physical capital has two unintuitive properties that creates a potential for it to be produced at much lower cost, despite the intuition that “physical = slow to build”.
Physical constraints on the replication rate of capital goods do exist, but in at least one major case are far from binding. Solar panels, for example, require ~1 year to pay back their energy cost. If solar panels were the only source of electricity, GDP could not grow at >100% per year while remaining equally electricity intensive. But this is far, far, above any predicted rate of economic growth, even “explosive” growth, which Davidson and Erdil and Besiroglu define to start at 30% per year.
I see a strong possibility that if human-level skilled labor were free, the capital stock could grow at an unprecedented rate.
A concrete suggestion for economists who want to avoid bad intuitions about AI but find themselves cringing at technologists’ beliefs about economics: learn about economic history.
It’s a powerful way to broaden one’s field of view with regard to what economic structures are possible, and the findings do not depend on speculation about the future, or taking Silicon Valley people seriously at all.
I tried my hand at this in this post, but I’m not an economist. A serious economist or economic historian can do much better.