In the end, despite cheaper feed, the daily cost of horse upkeep (the horse’s subsistence wage, if you will) was higher than the horse’s productivity in its transport and agricultural roles.
Presumably the absolute productivity of a horse (the amount of land it can plow or stuff it can haul) has not changed. So this only makes sense if the market value of the horse's labor has declined even faster than the price of feed. Is that the case?
Hmm, before you forced me to think harder about it, I was also thinking it basically comes down to the market value of the horse's labor versus the price of feed. But you're right that it's not clear why tractors should decrease the market value of horse labor more than they reduce the cost of feed. To the contrary, by replacing horses they directly reduce demand for feed (lowering short-run prices, at least), in addition to the broader boost they give to agricultural efficiency overall.
Now I'm thinking the thing missing from that analysis is the other costs to keeping a horse. I am guessing those remained relatively stable (like horse productivity), but perhaps that stability is the issue. In contrast to the feed, other horse upkeep costs were not brought down by the tractor: shelter, veterinary help, and the farmer's time required for horse care. So maybe the main story is the horse's revenue product falling below those types of horse costs. (Tractors also have analogous costs, but presumably those are lower, proportionally.)
edit: Or maybe the answer is more to do with the fixed upfront costs of purchasing a horse (versus a tractor)? If so, that would seem to complicate the analogy with human employment.
edit2: Sonnet 4 is telling me lifetime horse upkeep costs (circa 1920) were 40x the purchase price, and feed made up half or less of the daily upkeep. So I guess it's mostly about the non-feed upkeep costs. (The upfront cost is a bigger deal for tractors. In terms of operating costs, tractors have the advantage of very low costs when idle.)
I'm pondering editing the post to discuss this explicitly and acknowledge that it does weaken the analogy with AGI and humans. The issue is that AGI could bring down the costs more broadly than tractors did, which raises the question of why the marginal revenue product of labor would fall more quickly than the subsistence wage?
Thinking out loud, the thing is that there are analogs to the non-feed upkeep costs (shelter and farmer/veterinarian labor) for humans. Though some work, like composing poems, requires little more than physical sustenance to be performed well, most human production requires complementary inputs, principally various equipment or machinery. The question then comes down to whether you want to invest in such human-augmenting equipment as opposed to a fully automated solution.
For example, suppose total production is . Then optimal capital allocation means so that human-augmenting capital falls as robot productivity increases relative to human-in-the-loop productivity. Then the real wage, the marginal product of labor, is proportional to . If both and grow exponentially, the condition for the wage to remain constant is that grow at a rate times the rate at which grows (where is traditionally taken to be ). (Google Sheet simulation)
In this toy model, it is conceptually possible that human-augmenting technology, , advances sufficiently quickly relative to full automation, , to keep humans fully employed (at above subsistence wages) indefinitely. (And sufficiently deliberate policy could help.) But if, instead, continues growing at 1-2% annually while takes off at 10%+ rates of growth, human labor eventually becomes obsolete (in this toy model).
This seems like a whole other essay, rather than an edit to this one, though. I'm guessing the analogy to for horses was relatively fixed during 1910-1960.
I think the question of ai controlled humanoid robots vs humans and horses vs cars is interesting. RethinkX on this subject is kinda scary. Humanoid robots amortized over 3 years and say 16-20 hours a day quickly go below minimum wage in America so the question of whether the economy has enough tasks for such a labor revolution that starts out not very general, but becomes more general use over time. So I encourage your thoughts on this topic, as I don’t know what framework to use to think about it
Interesting, this is the first I've heard of them. Thanks, I'll check this out: https://www.rethinkx.com/labor
Yeah, I think instead the numbers only work out if you include things like the cost of land, or the cost of the farmer's time - and then what's risen is not the "subsistence cost of horses" per se, but a more general "cost of the things the simplified model of horse productivity didn't take into account."
Early tractor models really were an imperfect substitute for horses
Can you say any more about this point?
Here's Olmstead and Rhode:
The early gasoline tractors of the 1900s were behemoths, patterned after the giant steam plows that preceded them. They were useful for plowing, harrowing, and belt work but not for cultivating fields of growing crops nor powering farm equipment in tow. Innovative efforts between 1910 and 1940 vastly improved the machine's versatility and reduced its size, making it suited to a wider range of farms and tasks. ...
...the revolutionary McCormick-Deering Farmall (1924) was the first general-purpose tractor capable of cultivating amongst growing row crops. The latter machine was also among the first to incorporate a power-takeoff, enabling it to transfer power directly to implements under tow. A host of allied innovations such as improved air and oil filters, stronger implements, pneumatic tires, and the Ferguson three-point hitch and hydraulic system greatly increased the tractor's life span and usefulness. Seemingly small changes often yielded enormous returns in terms of cost, durability, and performance. As an example, rubber tires reduced vibrations thereby extending machine life, enhanced the tractor's usefulness in hauling (a task previously done by horses)... The greater mobility afforded by rubber tires also allowed farmers to use a tractor on widely separated fields.
The broader point is that, analogously, AI is only a suitable substitute for humans in narrow tasks today. But that should not be taken to preclude the possibility of total replacement later (except where, like with horse racing, literal humans are explicitly required).
Check out the Olmstead-Rhode paper cited in footnote 14. That was my main source for such specifics. I only have a minute at the moment or I would look myself and offer a better answer---I hope to come back to this. (My recollection is that they initially had hard tires and were difficult to maneuver?)
The economist Wassily Leontief, writing in 1966, used the then-recent decline of horses to make vivid what he foresaw as the coming impact of technological advances on workers. In 1910, the horse had remained indispensable for farming, transportation, and even war, despite decades of the radical technological progress of the Second Industrial Revolution. By 1960, though, horses were obsolete for all of the above, the US horse population having fallen by 85% as a result.
In 1982, when unemployment topped 10%, continuing an apparent "chronic increase in unemployment from one oscillation of the business cycle to the next,"[1] Leontief's warning of a similar fate for humans seemed on track. But the chronic increase ended there, with unemployment generally remaining far below its 1982 high ever since.[2] Median real wages have also not fallen as Leontief feared.[3]
Today Leontief's analogy between human and horse employment is scoffed at by most economists,[4] tainted by its association with failed predictions, but the analogy itself remains worth pondering. Examples from earlier horse history can actually help illustrate the reasons technological progress has continued benefiting workers despite naysayers—the reasons economists tend to give for optimism about the future of work. And understanding how those economics lessons apply to horses as well as humans then helps to sharpen the question raised by the ultimate decline of horses.
Through all the immense economic transformations that took place during the 600 years prior to 1900, the horse remained central to the English, and later the U.S., economy. Even controlling for human population growth, horses per capita remained stable or even increased during this period. Any predictions of the horse’s demise due to technological progress proved repeatedly mistaken.
A basic pessimistic mistake is to assume that increasing productivity directly decreases employment. Known as the “lump of labor fallacy,” this way of thinking imagines there is a fixed amount of work to be done.
For example, the golden age of canals began in England around 1750. A horse towing cargo floating in a canal can effectively pull 50 times as much weight as a horse pulling cargo in a cart on land, so some observers predicted that many fewer horses would be needed for transport once the canals were complete. In reality, however, the amount of work that needed doing was not fixed. The demand for goods transport greatly increased as the canals made it more efficient and affordable. But the amount of goods transported greatly increased due to the much more efficient canals being available.
It is hard to say whether goods transport along the canal routes grew so much that more horses were employed along those routes than before.[5] But aggregate demand for horses grew, or at least remained steady, overall.
The emergence of the steam engine in the mid-1800’s posed a more serious challenge to the horse’s role in transport, in particular. One horse-drawn coach service owner in 1831 used the word “annihilation” to describe what he foresaw.[6] And that description was apt for coach services in direct competition with rail lines. For instance, between Liverpool and Manchester, twenty-nine daily coaches in early 1830 dwindled to just one by 1833.[7]
However, it soon became apparent that the decline in demand for long-distance horse transport would be more than offset by increased demand for local “feeder” transportation. A narrow substitute for one horse task proved to be a complement to horse labor in aggregate. The steam locomotive, in displacing horses from the task of long-distance transport, effectively created many more new jobs for horses in what is today called “last mile” transport.
The horse population in England thus continued to grow throughout the 1800’s. Though it declined overall on a per-capita basis as the population became more urban,[8] horse employment in transportation in particular quadrupled between 1851 and 1901.[9] Meanwhile, even horses per capita continued growing through 1900 in the less urbanized U.S.[10]
Through 1900, then, horse employment remained strong despite dramatic technological changes. Myriad horse-augmenting innovations over the centuries, of which the canal was just one, had increased horse productivity many times over. But there is not a fixed lump of horse work needed because, ultimately, human desire is not satiable. And even in cases in which horses were completely displaced from certain tasks, rail transport being perhaps most prominent, new tasks were created for horses elsewhere.
Vehicles powered by the internal combustion engine, however, proved such a general substitute for horses that horse employment plummeted during the first half of the 1900’s.
This collapse in horse demand came despite reassurances that the horse could never be entirely replaced. As a 1915 tractor sales booklet put it, “Some horses will always have to be kept…to do the light jobs.”[11] Moreover, tractors would benefit horses, according to a 1915 Prairie Farmer magazine: "Do not do away with the horse, but take away the heavy burdens from his shoulder – that is the tractor farming idea. … Horses are kept in better condition and better spirits..."[12]
Early tractor models really were an imperfect substitute for horses. Even in 1940, a majority of farms reported having horses or mules but no tractors, with only 5% of farms reporting the opposite.[13] But in the face of ongoing incremental improvements in the machines, it would have been a mistake to project forward a prominent role for horses indefinitely.
Unlike with canals and railways, the internal combustion engine eventually displaced horses from effectively all roles in production. Tractors and motor vehicles incrementally improved to become general substitutes for horses. By 1950, the U.S. horse population had declined 70% from its peak. It declined further to 85% below peak in 1960.
The endpoint of horse employment provides a serious counter to economic arguments that technological unemployment is somehow impossible. It suggests that, if legitimate AGI is indeed achieved, there is no economic law that prevents permanent mass unemployment.
However, some prominent economists seem to believe technological unemployment is effectively impossible. They point to the law of comparative advantage, the fact that humans will always have a relative advantage in some tasks. As Joel Mokyr et al. (2015) put it: “Technophobic predictions about the future of the labor market sometimes suggest that computers and robots will have an absolute and comparative advantage over humans in all activities, which is nonsensical. … The law of comparative advantage strongly suggests that most workers will still have useful tasks to perform even in an economy where the capacities of robots and automation have increased considerably.”[14]
To understand why comparative advantage did not save the horse, consider a simplified example. Suppose a horse could plow 1 acre a day or transport 5 ton-miles a day, whereas a tractor could plow 5 acres daily or transport 50 ton-miles. The horse has a comparative advantage in plowing: its opportunity cost of plowing an acre is 5 ton-miles of transport, as opposed to 10 ton-miles for the tractor. Suppose you have one horse and one tractor, with three acres to plow per day, and you can rent out your remaining capacity for transport at the going rate. If upkeep cost were not a factor, you would want to use your horse for plowing one of your acres, leaving your tractor free for an additional 10 ton-miles of transport.
Unfortunately, keeping a horse does have costs. And if the profit from those extra 10 ton-miles is less than the daily cost of feeding the horse, it would be more profitable to instead send it off for slaughter unemployment.[15] Comparative advantage is irrelevant if the absolute level of productivity is below that minimum threshold.
With regard to horse upkeep, though, the cost of horse feed came down historically as tractor use increased, lowering the minimum productivity threshold for keeping horses employed.[16] The price of hay fell by half between 1910 and 1930. But, while this and other general equilibrium effects made the transition from tractors to horses more gradual than it otherwise would have been,[17] these countervailing effects were not enough to preserve horse employment indefinitely.
For humans, likewise, goods being made cheaper by AI would not guarantee that real wages, the purchasing power of labor earnings, go up. Nor would it necessarily prevent the marginal product of labor from falling below the amount required for subsistence.
In the end, despite cheaper feed, the daily cost of horse upkeep (the horse’s subsistence wage, if you will) was higher than the horse’s productivity in its transport and agricultural roles. The jobs that still remain for horses, such as horse racing and pony rides, tend to require literally being a horse.[18]
Leontief, Wassily W. “The Distribution of Work and Income.” Scientific American 247, no. 3 (1982): 188–205, p. 190.
Of course, they also haven’t risen appreciably above their 1979 level: https://fred.stlouisfed.org/series/LES1252881900Q
An NYT column put it this way in 2016, "Most economists still reject Professor Leontief’s analogy, but the conventional economic consensus is starting to fray." The conventional consensus was subsequently strengthened again as fiscal expansion kept the unemployment rate falling to its lowest point since the 60's in 2019, together with a stabilizing labor share of income. A 2024 World Economic Forum article exemplifies how the horse analogy continues to be portrayed, as part of "a long history" of "failed predictions," an "ahistorical" "dystopian narrative" "doomsayers cling to" in their "angst."
It seems trendy to refer to such cases, basically cases in which demand is elastic, as the Jevons paradox.
Ibid.
England’s population went from 30% urban in 1800 to 50% in 1850 and approximately 80% by 1900. https://lrhmatters.com/drivers-of-health/urbanisation-and-disease-in-industrializing-britain
Thompson, F. M. L. “Nineteenth-Century Horse Sense.” The Economic History Review, vol. 29, no. 1, 1976, pp. 60–81. JSTOR, https://doi.org/10.2307/2594507 . Accessed 12 May 2025.
The U.S. population was still just 15% urban in 1850 and remained below 40% urban by 1900, only reaching 80% around 2010. (These figures are likely not directly comparable with those for England in the previous footnote, however.) https://lboustan.scholar.princeton.edu/sites/g/files/toruqf4146/files/lboustan/files/research21_urban_handbook.pdf
International Harvester's 1915 book "Farm Power" https://www.gasenginemagazine.com/farm-life/tractors-get-the-nod-over-horses-in-1915/
19% reported owning both horses/mules and tractors. See Table 2 in Olmstead, Alan L., and Paul W. Rhode. “Reshaping the Landscape: The Impact and Diffusion of the Tractor in American Agriculture, 1910-1960.” The Journal of Economic History 61, no. 3 (2001): 663–98.
Mokyr, Joel, Chris Vickers, and Nicolas L. Ziebarth. “The History of Technological Anxiety and the Future of Economic Growth: Is This Time Different?” Journal of Economic Perspectives 29, no. 3 (August 1, 2015): 31–50. https://doi.org/10.1257/jep.29.3.31. I am not the first economist to wish that they would address the horse analogy: https://www.bradford-delong.com/2015/09/highlighted-the-history-of-technological-anxiety-and-the-future-of-economic-growth-is-this-time-different.html
Somewhat reassuringly, due at least in part to "the value that many humans placed on their bonds with horses," historically "many farmers retained their old stock even after adopting machines and, at least up through the 1940s, relatively few of the displaced horses and mules were sent to slaughter. ...only 19 thousand, or 6 percent, of the 314 thousand horses and mules disappearing off farms in 1940 were slaughtered in federally inspected meat plants. ... The number and share slaughtered rose over the late 1940s and early 1950s, but at the peak less than one-half of the disappearing animals met their end in this way." See n. 35 in Olmstead, Alan L., and Paul W. Rhode. “Reshaping the Landscape: The Impact and Diffusion of the Tractor in American Agriculture, 1910-1960.” The Journal of Economic History 61, no. 3 (2001): 663–98.
In terms of the analogy with human workers, the purchasing power of horse wages increased (though the wage measured in terms of oats remained the same).
Olmstead, Alan L., and Paul W. Rhode. “Reshaping the Landscape: The Impact and Diffusion of the Tractor in American Agriculture, 1910-1960.” The Journal of Economic History 61, no. 3 (2001): 663–98.
Hat tip to @Zvi for the “literally” phrasing.